The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc

上传人:文库蛋蛋多 文档编号:4178667 上传时间:2023-04-09 格式:DOC 页数:5 大小:52KB
返回 下载 相关 举报
The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc_第1页
第1页 / 共5页
The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc_第2页
第2页 / 共5页
The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc_第3页
第3页 / 共5页
The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc_第4页
第4页 / 共5页
The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc_第5页
第5页 / 共5页
亲,该文档总共5页,全部预览完了,如果喜欢就下载吧!
资源描述

《The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《The renminbi exchange rate and the global monetary system.doc(5页珍藏版)》请在三一办公上搜索。

1、The Renminbi Exchange Rate and the Global Monetary SystemJohn WilliamsonInstitute for International Economics Outline of a lecture delivered at the Central University of Finance and EconomicsBeijing, ChinaOctober 29, 2003 China may not welcome the attention that has been bestowed on the question of

2、the renminbi exchange rate in recent months, but it is a symptom of the fact that the country has emerged as a significant force in the global economy. That attention is not going to go away. China must learn to live with its new role, just as the rest of the world has to learn to live with an emerg

3、ent China. It is an honor to have this opportunity of contributing to the process of thinking through what that implies.I propose to address three topics in this lecture. First, I will try and explain what I mean by a fundamental equilibrium exchange rate (FEER) and describe how it is calculated. Se

4、cond, I will examine what this approach suggests about the desirable value of the renminbi at the present time. I will argue that a substantial renminbi appreciation is indeed desirable, including from the standpoint of Chinas own needs. Third, I will explain why I believe the Chinese authorities we

5、re right to reject the suggestion that they should abolish capital controls and float the renminbi.The Concept and Measurement of the FEERThe term fundamental equilibrium exchange rate was introduced to emphasize that in thinking about what a countrys exchange rate should be one ought not to focus o

6、n a momentary market equilibrium. One ought instead to think about what in the IMFs original Articles was referred to as fundamental disequilibrium, which meant an exchange rate at which it would not be possible to achieve simultaneously both of the basic objectives of macroeconomic policy. These we

7、re usually formulated as internal balance, meaning non-inflationary full employment or a similar concept, and external balance, meaning a balance of payments position that appeared sustainable and desirable. The idea was that an overvalued exchange rate would imply either deflating the economy or ru

8、nning an unsustainable payments deficit; conversely for an undervalued rate. Fundamental equilibrium holds where neither of those undesirable outcomes prevails.Naturally the FEER refers to the real effective exchange rate, since this is what influences macroeconomic outcomes. China is currently foll

9、owing an exchange rate policy that results in a highly unstable exchange rate in that sense. By holding the bilateral nominal exchange rate against the dollar constant in a period when the dollar has strongly depreciated, China has itself depreciated (it has ridden the dollar down). Some of us were

10、surprised, and dismayed, to hear senior Chinese officials describing their governments policy as one of holding a fixed exchange rate; it is most certainly not fixed in the sense that matters to macroeconomic policy.One can often get a rough idea of whether an exchange rate is overvalued, in fundame

11、ntal equilibrium, or undervalued by a cursory examination of a countrys macroeconomic situation. If a countrys economy is overheating at the same time that it has a bigger current account surplus (or a smaller current account deficit) than is needed to maintain a sustainable balance of payments posi

12、tion for the foreseeable future, then its currency is undervalued. If the economy is underemployed and it is losing reserves because of a current account deficit larger than can be financed by sustainable capital inflows, then its currency is overvalued.More difficult cases occur when different indi

13、cators point in different directions. Then a macroeconometric model of some sort is essential to reach a judgment. If, for example, the economy is overheating but the country has an unsustainable payments deficit, then one needs to ask what the situation would be when the excess demand had been elim

14、inated. To answer that question convincingly demands some sort of a model, though in that case a rather simple model might suffice. If one concludes that mere elimination of excess demand pressure would look after the balance of payments, then the currency is not overvalued; indeed, it is conceivabl

15、e that once the economy reached internal balance the payments position might be in an unsustainable surplus, in which case the currency would actually be undervalued.If one concludes that a currency is misaligned, then the next issue is to decide by how much. This again inevitably requires the use o

16、f some form of quantitative macroeconometric model, though again it may be crude (or even implicit). The sort of model needed here is rather old-fashioned, being one that explains current account outcomes by a measure of economic activity and the real exchange rate.1 That enables one to calculate th

17、e change in the real exchange rate needed to achieve a target current account when activity is at some normal, sustainable level. No one doubts that there are lots of other interesting issues to consider, such as how to achieve the exchange rate that the analysis indicates to be desirable, but that

18、does not make the simple model illegitimate. One also needs, either as part of the same model or independently, a way of estimating the change in the nominalexchange rate needed to achieve the desired change in the real exchange rate, given that depreciation can be expected to cause some inflation t

19、hat will reduce the change in the real exchange rate.However, exchange rates are inherently the business of more than one country. A small country can expect that the rest of the world will allow it to choose its exchange rate without too much interference, but large countries have to recognize that

20、 their partners have a legitimate interest in what they choose because their choice influences those partners effective exchange rates. It is for this reason that I have always emphasized that FEERs need to be calculated simultaneously for all the large countries, as a general equilibrium exercise.

21、One needs to ask what set of exchange rates would yield a set of mutually satisfactory balance of payments outcomes when all the economies are at reasonably full employment. To do that one certainly needs to use a formal macroeconometric model.If it were true that countries cannot in principle achie

22、ve a set of mutually satisfactory balance of payments outcomes, because countries have antithetical payments objectives, then the exercise I have described would be impossible. There are economists -mostly self-styled Keynesians who do not believe that output is constrained by supply but only by dem

23、and-who believe that all countries have a national interest in securing a bigger current account surplus. Most of us regard this as mercantilist rubbish. If output is usually constrained from the supply side, then a more competitive exchange rate has a disadvantage in curbing the resources available

24、 for investment as well as an advantage in simulating the desire to invest. The growth-maximizing exchange rate will be that at which these two forces balance one another at the margin.Assuming that it is not impossible in principle, one still needs to devise a set of current account outcomes that a

25、ll countries would recognize to be desirable. This is something that (in association with Molly Mahar) I attempted to do as one of the bases for the calculation of FEERs by Simon Wren-Lewis and Rebecca Driver (1998). I have repeated the exercise in a draft paper for a conference that the Institute f

26、or International Economics plans to hold in the coming months about the completion of the correction of the dollars overvaluation of recent years (Williamson 2003). I will refer to the assumptions made about China in the following section. For the moment the point is merely that one needs a set of c

27、onsistent current account outcomes as an input for a model of the world economy that will calculate a set of target exchange rates. If the inputs add up (allowing for the world statistical discrepancy), then the resulting target exchange rates (the FEERs) will also be consistent.Application to the R

28、enminbiRecent evidence would seem to indicate that the Chinese economy is overheating. Bank loans are expanding at a frenetic rate and the pace of investment recalls what happened in other Asian countries in the days before the East Asian crisis. The statistics tell us that China has been in current

29、 account surplus for a long time. Not only that, but it has been a net capital importer, as befits a country that is stil underdeveloped but has the fundamentals in place to permit rapid growth if it invests a lot. Because of those two factors together, Chinese reserves have grown to a point where t

30、hey are now the second highest in the world (after Japan). In other words, China has an external surplus on any criterion one can think of. China thus falls into one of the cases that are easy to diagnose, where both internal and external considerations point to the desirability of a currency revalu

31、ation. This would relieve tensions in the domestic economy as well as diminish the external surplus and reserve accumulation.A number of reasons have been advanced for resisting an appreciation and maintaining the dollar peg at an unchanged value.1. Chinas current account surplus has recently dimini

32、shed and will fall further as a consequence of the import liberalization being undertaken to qualify for WTO membership. Yes, the surplus has fallen, but it is still a surplus rather than the deficit that is appropriate for a country in Chinas situation. And if the domestic economy were to be stabil

33、ized (excess demand were to be eliminated), the surplus would grow again. Yes, import liberalization is helping to expand imports and thus reduce the surplus, but the forthcoming abolition of the Multi-Fibre Arrangement will give scope for a substantial expansion of Chinas exports of textiles and ap

34、parel, thus tending to increase its surplus.2. If China were to liberalize capital outflows, then there could be a large increase in the outflow of capital and reserve accumulation might well go into reverse. That is true, but it constitutes an argument against precipitate liberalization of capital

35、outflows, not against a revaluation. The reason that many Chinese might want to export capital is not that the domestic return on capital is low, but that they fear a banking crisis once other individuals gain the freedom to withdraw their savings and ship them abroad. The answer is to delay liberal

36、ization of capital outflows at least until the banking system has been cleaned up. That clean-up will be delayed the longer the flood of reserves keeps enabling the banking system to make excessive loans, many of which are likely to go bad when times turn difficult.3. Chinas policy of exchange rate

37、stability has helped to stabilize the Asian economy, e.g. during the Asian currency crisis in 1997. It is certainly true that Chinas refusal to devalue at that difficult time helped limit the scope of the crisis. However, the fact that China was able to pursue that policy even at that time shows tha

38、t its payments position was strong even then, and it has become much stronger since with the turnaround in Asias position. A policy of riding the dollar down makes all other Asian competitors fearful of allowing their currencies to join in the needed general appreciation against the dollar, which is

39、 hardly a contribution to stability in the present context.4. A revaluation would threaten Chinese growth and, because of that, might not even diminish the balance of payments surplus. If growth depended solely on demand, this would make sense. But in fact supply, not demand, limitations are current

40、ly constraining Chinese growth. Investment is very high (42 percent of GDP, according to my colleague Morris Goldstein) and being financed by a dangerously rapid growth in bank lending. A renminbi revaluation would provide a little bit more scope for this investment, and would encourage the expansio

41、n of consumption. It would also slow the reserve accumulation that underlies the rapid credit expansion. This would diminish the chance of the process ending with a financial crisis, which really would damage Chinese growth.In short, the reasons that have been advanced for rejecting an appreciation

42、are unpersuasive.How large a revaluation would be desirable? That depends on how large an adjustment is deemed to be appropriate. In 1996, Molly Mahar and I postulated a current account deficit of 2.8 percent of GDP as a reasonable objective for China over the following years, on the grounds that Ch

43、ina is a developing country that can expect to invest productively an excess of domestic investment over the savings generated at home.2 We thought that China would have no difficulty in importing enough capital to finance such a deficit. In fact, China has imported capital, but on a somewhat smalle

44、r scale than this, around 1 percent of GDP on average. Perhaps it could have imported more capital if it had been trying to, of course. But in the draft of my new paper on the topic (Williamson 2003), I postulate a target of current account balance-admittedly more as a result of applying mechanicall

45、y an algorithm that seemed to give reasonable results in general than because I was intellectually convinced that China ought not to be targeting a current account deficit.The suggestion of my colleagues Morris Goldstein and Nicholas Lardy that China should target a current account deficit of some 1

46、 percent of GDP, to put it in overall balance given the 1 percent capital inflows, seems as reasonable as any. They have stated (in the Asian Wall Street Journal, 12 September 2003) that their calculations suggest a revaluation of 15 to 25 percent. The Director of my Institute, Fred Bergsten, has ta

47、ken the top half of this range (20 to 25 percent) as his figure. My own guess is that even this may be somewhat conservative: I think it important that any adjustment be big enough to convince market participants that the change is complete, not a first step, since otherwise a revaluation may simply

48、 serve to encourage more speculative inflows. But none of us has a satisfactory macroeconometric model at our disposal to back up our estimates or guesses. After a first step revaluation I agree with my colleagues that China should operate its foreign exchange market with wider margins and should ch

49、ange its peg from the US dollar to a basket of the three major currencies. It should be more willing to contemplate changes in the value of the peg, while keeping each individual change in the peg small so as to avoid creating strong speculative pressures.The Dangers of Premature LiberalizationWhile I am critical of the Chinese resistance to a revaluation of the renminbi, I believe that the Chinese authorities were absolutely right to resist the call of US Secretary of the Treasury John Snow for a liber

展开阅读全文
相关资源
猜你喜欢
相关搜索

当前位置:首页 > 办公文档 > 其他范文


备案号:宁ICP备20000045号-2

经营许可证:宁B2-20210002

宁公网安备 64010402000987号